Part of a series on |
Economics |
---|
In economics, diminishing returns are the decrease in marginal (incremental) output of a production process as the amount of a single factor of production is incrementally increased, holding all other factors of production equal (ceteris paribus).[1] The law of diminishing returns (also known as the law of diminishing marginal productivity) states that in productive processes, increasing a factor of production by one unit, while holding all other production factors constant, will at some point return a lower unit of output per incremental unit of input.[2][3] The law of diminishing returns does not cause a decrease in overall production capabilities, rather it defines a point on a production curve whereby producing an additional unit of output will result in a loss and is known as negative returns. Under diminishing returns, output remains positive, but productivity and efficiency decrease.
The modern understanding of the law adds the dimension of holding other outputs equal, since a given process is understood to be able to produce co-products.[4] An example would be a factory increasing its saleable product, but also increasing its CO2 production, for the same input increase.[2] The law of diminishing returns is a fundamental principle of both micro and macro economics and it plays a central role in production theory.[5]
The law of diminishing returns was one of the economic principles. It was the concept of classic economic theory.[6] There were some common examples in this concept. For example, social media marketing. When we attempt that using social media marketing will double the profits, however, there could be a chance for great amount of information that published out to public and caused decreasing in profits. In this situation, marketing department should adjust the other variables which were the social media channels they have used, monitoring and analysing. Another example was the agriculture. Assuming the farm increased the number of labours for the purpose of increasing yield of crops. However, additional labours will produce less than their expectations and even before increasing of labours. This was the law of diminishing return. The farm's productivity became less efficient than before. Last example was enterprise resource planning. It was extremely important for enterprises to record the point of diminishing return. It will be efficient for the enterprises to monitor and analysis in future. For receiving more precise information or data, enterprises must get through with their customers and understand their demands and expectations.
The concept of diminishing returns can be explained by considering other theories such as the concept of exponential growth.[7] It is commonly understood that growth will not continue to rise exponentially, rather it is subject to different forms of constraints such as limited availability of resources and capitalisation which can cause economic stagnation.[8] This example of production holds true to this common understanding as production is subject to the four factors of production which are land, labour, capital and enterprise.[9] These factors have the ability to influence economic growth and can eventually limit or inhibit continuous exponential growth.[10] Therefore, as a result of these constraints the production process will eventually reach a point of maximum yield on the production curve and this is where marginal output will stagnate and move towards zero.[11] Innovation in the form of technological advances or managerial progress can minimise or eliminate diminishing returns to restore productivity and efficiency and to generate profit.[12]
This idea can be understood outside of economics theory, for example, population. The population size on Earth is growing rapidly, but this will not continue forever (exponentially). Constraints such as resources will see the population growth stagnate at some point and begin to decline.[7] Similarly, it will begin to decline towards zero but not actually become a negative value, the same idea as in the diminishing rate of return inevitable to the production process.
The concept of diminishing returns can be traced back to the concerns of early economists such as Johann Heinrich von Thünen, Jacques Turgot, Adam Smith,[13] James Steuart, Thomas Robert Malthus, and [14] David Ricardo. In the past centuries, economists still confused about marginal returns with homogeneous inputs in short-run or long-run. In the 18th century, the law of diminishing returns origin by Jacques Turgot in his work. He stated that doubling on expenditure in terms of monetary expenditures in agriculture will double the returns. Previously, Adam Smith did not stated the concept of diminishing returns in his work. However, in 1815, David Ricardo, Thomas Malthus, Edward West, and Robert Torrens published the concept of the law of diminishing returns applied to the land rent. These works were relevant to the investigation by the committees of Parliament on reason of grain prices in England reduced. By the conclusion stated by the four economists, the prices of the products were risen due to the Napoleonic Wars. Napoleonic Wars have affected the international trade and causing the farmers moved to the lands which were undeveloped and far away. In addition, due to the end of the Napoleonic Wars, the grain of imports restored and causing the decline in prices because the farmers need to attract customers and sell their products more faster.[15] Classical economists such as Malthus and Ricardo attributed the successive diminishment of output to the decreasing quality of the inputs whereas Neoclassical economists assume that each "unit" of labor is identical. Diminishing returns are due to the disruption of the entire production process as additional units of labor are added to a fixed amount of capital. The law of diminishing returns remains an important consideration in areas of production such as farming and agriculture.
Proposed on the cusp of the First Industrial Revolution, it was motivated with single outputs in mind. In recent years, economists since the 1970s have sought to redefine the theory to make it more appropriate and relevant in modern economic societies.[4] Specifically, it looks at what assumptions can be made regarding number of inputs, quality, substitution and complementary products, and output co-production, quantity and quality.
The origin of the law of diminishing returns was developed primarily within the agricultural industry. In the early 19th century, David Ricardo as well as other English economists previously mentioned, adopted this law as the result of the lived experience in England after the war. It was developed by observing the relationship between prices of wheat and corn and the quality of the land which yielded the harvests.[16] The observation was that at a certain point, that the quality of the land kept increasing, but so did the cost of produce etc. Therefore, each additional unit of labour on agricultural fields, actually provided a diminishing or marginally decreasing return.[17]
A common example of diminishing returns is choosing to hire more people on a factory floor to alter current manufacturing and production capabilities. Given that the capital on the floor (e.g. manufacturing machines, pre-existing technology, warehouses) is held constant, increasing from one employee to two employees is, theoretically, going to more than double production possibilities and this is called increasing returns.
If 50 people are employed, at some point, increasing the number of employees by two percent (from 50 to 51 employees) would increase output by two percent and this is called constant returns.
Further along the production curve at, for example 100 employees, floor space is likely getting crowded, there are too many people operating the machines and in the building, and workers are getting in each other's way. Increasing the number of employees by two percent (from 100 to 102 employees) would increase output by less than two percent and this is called "diminishing returns."
After achieving the point of maximum output, employing additional workers, this will give negative returns.[18]
Through each of these examples, the floor space and capital of the factor remained constant, i.e., these inputs were held constant. By only increasing the number of people, eventually the productivity and efficiency of the process moved from increasing returns to diminishing returns.
To understand this concept thoroughly, acknowledge the importance of marginal output or marginal returns. Returns eventually diminish because economists measure productivity with regard to additional units (marginal). Additional inputs significantly impact efficiency or returns more in the initial stages.[19] The point in the process before returns begin to diminish is considered the optimal level. Being able to recognize this point is beneficial, as other variables in the production function can be altered rather than continually increasing labor.
Further, examine something such as the Human Development Index, which would presumably continue to rise so long as GDP per capita (in Purchasing Power Parity terms) was increasing. This would be a rational assumption because GDP per capita is a function of HDI. Even GDP per capita will reach a point where it has a diminishing rate of return on HDI.[20] Just think, in a low income family, an average increase of income will likely make a huge impact on the wellbeing of the family. Parents could provide abundantly more food and healthcare essentials for their family. That is a significantly increasing rate of return. But, if you gave the same increase to a wealthy family, the impact it would have on their life would be minor. Therefore, the rate of return provided by that average increase in income is diminishing.
Signify
Increasing Returns:
Constant Returns:
Diminishing Returns:
There is a widely recognised production function in economics: Q= f(NR, L, K, t, E):
Start from the equation for the Marginal Product:
To demonstrate diminishing returns, two conditions are satisfied; marginal product is positive, and marginal product is decreasing.
Elasticity, a function of Input and Output, , can be taken for small input changes. If the above two conditions are satisfied, then .[23]
This works intuitively;
There is an inverse relationship between returns of inputs and the cost of production,[24] although other features such as input market conditions can also affect production costs. Suppose that a kilogram of seed costs one dollar, and this price does not change. Assume for simplicity that there are no fixed costs. One kilogram of seeds yields one ton of crop, so the first ton of the crop costs one dollar to produce. That is, for the first ton of output, the marginal cost as well as the average cost of the output is per ton. If there are no other changes, then if the second kilogram of seeds applied to land produces only half the output of the first (showing diminishing returns), the marginal cost would equal per half ton of output, or per ton, and the average cost is per 3/2 tons of output, or /3 per ton of output. Similarly, if the third kilogram of seeds yields only a quarter ton, then the marginal cost equals per quarter ton or per ton, and the average cost is per 7/4 tons, or /7 per ton of output. Thus, diminishing marginal returns imply increasing marginal costs and increasing average costs.
Cost is measured in terms of opportunity cost. In this case the law also applies to societies – the opportunity cost of producing a single unit of a good generally increases as a society attempts to produce more of that good. This explains the bowed-out shape of the production possibilities frontier.
Part of the reason one input is altered ceteris paribus, is the idea of disposability of inputs.[25] With this assumption, essentially that some inputs are above the efficient level. Meaning, they can decrease without perceivable impact on output, after the manner of excessive fertiliser on a field.
If input disposability is assumed, then increasing the principal input, while decreasing those excess inputs, could result in the same "diminished return", as if the principal input was changed certeris paribus. While considered "hard" inputs, like labour and assets, diminishing returns would hold true. In the modern accounting era where inputs can be traced back to movements of financial capital, the same case may reflect constant, or increasing returns.
It is necessary to be clear of the "fine structure"[4] of the inputs before proceeding. In this, ceteris paribus is disambiguating.